The Rediff Special / Jeffrey Sachs and Nirupam Bajpai
The need for tax reform
A key element of India's economic liberalisation has been tax
reform. New Delhi's tax reform strategy is largely based on the
Raja Chelliah Committee report. It proposed that the share of
customs duties in total taxes be reduced and the share of direct
taxes raised. More revenue needed to be mobilised via excise duties
by transforming them into value added taxes. Maximum rates of
personal and corporate income taxes were reduced.
Last year the Centre levied a new minimum alternate tax on firms
whose total income, after deductions, was below 30 per cent of
the book profit. If so the firm's income was deemed to be 30 per
cent and taxed accordingly. The effective rate worked out to 12
per cent of book profit calculated under the Companies Act.
Thanks to higher growth and tax reforms, tax revenues of Centre
and states, which fell from 16.7 per cent of gross domestic product
in 1991-92 to 15.2 the next year, recovered to almost 16 cent
in 1995-96. The loss in revenue was due to reduced customs and
excise duties as a result of the reforms started in 1991. Growth
made taxes buoyant again. The rise in Central tax revenue was
largely due to greater direct tax collection.
The Centre made reasonable progress over indirect taxes. Import
tariff reform aimed to reduce the cost of intermediate and capital
good imports and lower the protection provided to Indian industry.
Customs duties, though lowered, remain higher than India's competitors,
reducing India's attractiveness to investors.
Reforms of commodity taxation were initiated in 1993-94 to rationalise
the then existing excise-modified value added tax system. Under
MODVAT credit of duty is allowed on inputs used either for producing
excisable finished products or intermediate products. Over time
the ambit of MODVAT has expanded. But its conversion into a full
fledged VAT up to the manufacturing stage is far from complete.
Other Central excise duty reforms include cuts in the number of
ad valorem rates, phasing out of exemption notifications and simplifying
the procedure to value excise duty.
Briefly put, the increased
share of direct taxes, and decline in indirect taxes indicates
the tax reforms strategy since 1991 is basically working. But more
needs to be done. For both direct and indirect taxes, we suggest
measures to improve the yield of direct taxes. To augment revenue
from personal income tax, the government should broaden the tax
paying population. Base widening can be done in two ways: bring
large numbers of potential taxpayers into the net, and eliminate
the tax exemptions and deductions provided to serve non-tax objectives.
Attempts have been made to broaden the base of presumptive taxation,
where incomes are estimated by including shopkeepers, small
transport operators and the like. Later, a new estimated income
scheme for contractors with turnover up to Rs 40 million and for
owners of up to 10 trucks was introduced. Presumptive taxation
is suitable since evasion is rampant in the unorganised sector.
Easy to administer, such levies increase equity and efficiency
by taxing those who never paid taxes earlier.
The experience of countries like France, Israel and Turkey with
presumptive taxation is not encouraging. We don't expect significant
results. Nonetheless, India should continue to improve on the
scheme. A major reason people avoid the scheme is fear of getting
into the books of tax authorities. The relationship of the presumptive
tax to the rest of the tax system needs clarification. Extending
estimated income schemes to cover more activities would be worthwhile.
Base broadening can also be done by removing the exemptions and
deductions allowed on various grounds of social and economic policy.
Several incentive provisions have been withdrawn. Many remain.
A number of Income Tax Act concessions could be removed. This
would further help to lower tax rates. There is also a case for levying
tax on free or confessional rent accommodations provided to public
employees. Similarly, since restrictions on private sector salaries
have been removed, fringe benefits for such employees need to
be taxed.
State governments need to tax agricultural income. Small farmers
can be exempted. In the past 30 years agricultural incomes, especially
for large landowners, have risen considerably: particularly in
Punjab, Haryana, western Uttar Pradesh; deltaic West Bengal and
coastal Andhra Pradesh, Tamil Nadu, Kerala, coastal and eastern
Karnataka. The states need tax systems simple to administer, of
moderate rates and broad based.
Corporate taxation also needs to see an increase in the number
of taxpaying companies. There are many firms which pay hefty dividends
without paying income tax: zero tax companies. They used incentive
provisions in tax laws to show no taxable profits. The present
process of eliminating incentives was supposed to eradicate zero
tax companies. This has not happened. The persistence of the zero
tax firm points to a need to introduce a minimum tax in order
to improve fairness and revenue buoyancy.
Though a step in the right direction, MAT will not tackle under
reported profits through manipulate transfer pricing. Nor is it
applicable if there is no taxable income. In other words, if firms
post losses under both the Companies Act and the Income Tax Act.
Firms with enough investments to allow for depreciation provisions
could well show zero taxable income. Companies could charge the
same depreciation rates under the Companies Act in their books
as well, and thereby show zero book profits.
MAT may serve its
purpose better if levied on gross corporate assets instead of
book profits. Additional revenue of Rs 100 to 170 billion, about
one to 1.7 per cent of GDP, could be mobilized based on realistic
assumptions about coverage and a rate of return in the range of
1.6 to two per cent on the book value of assets.
Of the Centre's indirect taxes, consider first customs duties.
In the last five years import duties have plummeted. But India
needs to bring them down to east Asian levels. In the World Economic
Forum's list of 49 country tariff rates, India had the highest
in the sample.
The Chelliah committee recommended average tariff rates be brought
down to 25 per cent. We believe this to be thoroughly inadequate.
Most importantly, tariff rates on imported capital goods used
for export, and on imported inputs into export production, should
be duty free.
There is also the question of liberalising consumer goods imports.
Such liberalisation has not occurred because of misconceptions,
fears and ignorance of the benefits of liberalising such imports.
Protecting consumer goods industries diverts resources to inefficient
production, causing higher prices. Lack of international competition
leads to minimal quality upgrading in consumer sectors.
Another area of reform of indirect taxes is domestic commodity
taxation. Today's domestic commodity taxation. Today's system
is an excise-MODVAT framework. Reforms are required to make this
a comprehensive VAT at the central level. VAT is the major tax
instrument in many countries since it is practicable and avoids
cascading. Over time VAT will be instrumental in generating dynamic
efficiency gains. VAT has worked well in federations like Brazil,
Germany, Mexico and is being introduced in China and Pakistan.
Transformation to a VAT at the Central level needs to be supplemented
by reformed indirect taxes at the state level. Inefficient state
sales tax regimes and disharmony between Centre and state taxes
means indirect tax system as a whole remain complex and distortionary.
State sales tax rates differ: from six per cent in Orissa to 22
in Gujarat.
Some states are reforming sales taxes gradually. However,
most have yet to initiate tax reforms. In 1993 Kerala and Tamil
Nadu introduced VAT on some commodities. Some states, Like Madhya
Pradesh, Uttar Pradesh and West Bengal, are streamlining sales tax
administration.
We suggest India adopt a comprehensive VAT. The suggested tax
regime would constitute a national level VAT shared between Centre
and states.The revenue implications of the tax policies outlined
earlier cannot easily be calculated. We would expect to lose further
revenues through customs and to raise revenue via base broadening
and MAT. Conservatively the overall impact would be small, so
that MAT reform would finance further liberalisation on trade
taxation.
Jeffrey Sachs is professor of economics and Nirupam Bajpai
is a development associate at Harvard University. This is an extract
from their paper, Fiscal policy in India's economic reforms, and was published
before Finance Minister P Chidambaram presented his Budget on February 28.
Tell us what you think of this opinion
|